Page images
PDF
EPUB

The absence of a sharp antithesis between the taxes that have been approved and those that have been condemned is frankly recognized:

"As the property of companies engaged in such commerce may be taxed .., and may be taxed at its value as it is in its organic relations, and not merely as a congeries of unrelated items, taxes on such property have been sustained that took account of the augmentation of value from the commerce in which it was engaged. . . . Since the commercial value of property consists in the expectation of income from it, and since taxes ultimately, at least in the long run, come out of income, obviously taxes called taxes on property and those called taxes on income or receipts tend to run into each other somewhat as fair value and anticipated profits run into each other in the law of damages. The difficulty of distinguishing them became greater when it was decided, not without much debate and difference of opinion, that interstate carriers' property might be taxed as a going concern." 85

Then follows the reinterpretation of the Maine case and a quotation from Postal Telegraph Cable Co. v. Adams: 86

"By whatever name the exaction may be called, if it amounts to no more than the ordinary tax upon property or a just equivalent therefor, ascertained by reference thereto, it is not open to attack as inconsistent with the Constitution." 87

The question before the court is said to be" whether this is such a tax." 88 Mr. Justice Holmes paves the way for an answer by the following recapitulation and analysis:

"It appears sufficiently, perhaps from what has been said, that we are to look for a practical rather than a logical or philosophical distinction. The State must be allowed to tax the property and to tax it at its actual value as a going concern. On the other hand the State cannot tax the interstate business. The two necessities hardly admit of an absolute logical reconciliation. Yet the distinction is not without sense. When a

85 210 U. S. 225-26, 28 Sup. Ct. Rep. 638 (1908).

86 Note 69, supra.

87 155 U. S. 688, 697, 15 Sup. Ct. Rep. 268 (1895); quoted in 210 U. S. 217, 227, 28 Sup. Ct. Rep. 638 (1908). This same passage from the opinion in the Postal Telegraph case, together with what immediately precedes it, is quoted by Mr. Justice Day in United States Express Co. v. Minnesota, 223 U. S. 335, 347-48, 32 Sup. Ct. Rep. 211 (1912). See page 402, infra.

[blocks in formation]

legislature is trying simply to value property, it is less likely to attempt to or effect injurious regulation than when it is aiming directly at the receipts from interstate commerce. A practical line can be drawn by taking the whole scheme of taxation into account. That must be done by this court as best it can. Neither the state courts nor the legislatures, by giving the tax a particular name or by the use of some form of words, can take away our duty to consider its nature and effect. If it bears upon commerce among the States so directly as to amount to a regulation in a relatively immediate way, it will not be saved by name or form." 89

These canons were not difficult to apply to the Texas tax before the court. The value of the property as a going concern had already been reached by other taxes. To the argument of counsel for the state that "equal' implies, not identity, but duality," Mr. Justice Holmes replied:

" 90

"The distinction between a tax 'equal to' one per cent of gross receipts and a tax of one per cent of the same, seems to us nothing, except where the former phrase is the index of an actual attempt to reach the property and to let the interstate traffic and the receipts from it alone. We find no such attempt or anything to qualify the plain inference from the statute taken by itself." 91

The tax in question was said to be "merely an effort to reach the gross receipts, not even disguised by the name of an occupation tax, and in no way helped by the words 'equal to."" 92 It was added that "of course, it does not matter that the plaintiffs in error are domestic corporations or that the tax embraces indiscriminately gross receipts from commerce within as well as outside of the State." 93

89 210 U. S. 227, 28 Sup. Ct. Rep. 638 (1908).

90 Ibid., 223.

91 Ibid., 227.

92 Ibid., 228.

"Ibid., 228. Mr. Justice Harlan, on behalf of the minority, implied that it did matter that the corporation was a domestic one, for he says: "The plaintiff in error is a Texas corporation, and it cannot be doubted that the State may impose an occupation tax on one of its own corporations, provided such tax does not interfere with the exercise of some power belonging to the United States" (Ibid., 229-30). The proviso of course weakens the statement in logic, if not in judicial psychology; but later on page 229 in the passage quoted on page 385, supra, the dissenting opinion invokes the supposition that the state might impose on railroad corporations "of its own creation" an income tax, thus again implying that the domesticity of the corporation was a material element in the case.

It will be remembered that one of the grounds on which State Tax on Railway

The tax, then, was on the interstate business and not on the property at its value as a going concern. When we seek for the reason why this tax was not on the property as a going concern, we find that it is because there was another tax on the property as a going concern. The reason is not completely satisfying. Disregarding words and looking to substance, we do not readily perceive why one tax as well as the other cannot be on the property as a going concern, nor why one as well as the other is not on the business. There is ample reason why the legitimacy of one may depend on the presence or absence of the other, and there is no just ground for complaint because the court picked for slaughter the one that was before it. Since the state should not have both, but either would be allowable if alone, the designation of the good and the bad is wisely determined in accordance with the formal line of demarcation which the court had previously established. Mr. Justice Holmes correctly states the traditional theory that the state can tax the property at its value as a going concern, but cannot tax Gross Receipts, 15 Wall. (U. S.) 284 (1872), proceeded was that the corporation was a domestic one, and that this ground of the decision was not overruled in the Philadelphia Steamship case, note 19, supra. In 1875, Railroad Co. v. Maryland, 21 Wall. (U. S.) 456 (1874), considered in 31 HARV. L. REV. 578-79, sustained a charter provision requiring an interstate railroad corporation to pay to the chartering state semi-annually one-fifth of its total gross passenger receipts. Ashley v. Ryan, 153 U. S. 436, 14 Sup. Ct. Rep. 865 (1894), 31 HARV. L. REV. 580-81, and Kansas City, M. & B. R. R. Co. v. Stiles, 242 U. S. 111, 37 Sup. Ct. Rep. 58 (1916), 31 HARV. L. REV. 599–600, sustained charter provisions requiring a charter fee or an annual excise measured by total capital stock. The idea in these cases seemed to be that a state can put any price it pleases on the grant of a charter to be a corporation. International & G. N. Ry. Co. v. Anderson County, 246 U. S. 424, 38 Sup. Ct. Rep. 370 (1918), however, implies that provisions of a police character in corporate charters may by reason of changed conditions become invalid regulations of interstate commerce.

These cases, however, do not bear on the question involved in the Galveston case, because the tax there in issue was not a franchise tax, nor was it, so far as appears, on the statute book when the complainant was incorporated. The franchise was taxed as property under another statute. Though Texas had avoided naming the “subject" it had selected for taxation, it had by selecting certain kinds of corporations engaged in a certain kind of occupation, imposed an occupation tax. The state court had called it an occupation tax, and had strongly implied, if not specifically declared, in a passage in the opinion immediately preceding that quoted in note 76, supra, that this construction was necessary in order to sustain the tax under the state constitution. The exaction, therefore, had to stand or fall as an occupation tax, quite independently of any peculiar power of a state over its own corporate creatures. The Philadelphia Steamship case, note 19, supra, at pages 342-43, shows that where a state seeks to justify its exaction as one on the franchise of domestic corporations, it must clearly indicate that this is the power and the only power that it is exercising.

the interstate business. The gross-receipts tax before the court did not profess to be a property tax, whereas by another statute the franchise was subjected to an ad valorem tax as property.94 The state itself had chosen to call one a property tax and the other something else. It can hardly complain that the court accepts its designations in choosing which one to reject, and decides that it is less likely to effect injurious regulation of interstate commerce by the tax which it calls a property tax than by the one which is more directly on interstate receipts.

This traditional theory, as Mr. Justice Holmes announces, posits two necessities that do not admit of logical reconciliation. This is because a tax on the value of the property as a going concern is a tax on the value of the going concern, and the value of the going concern is the value of the business. It would make for simplicity and directness to recognize that a tax on the value of the business is a tax on the business. The business may be worth more or less than the reconstruction cost of the property less depreciation. Where the property has no alternative uses, its value, whatever its cost, cannot exceed the value of the business which it serves. In the case of that part of the property of a railroad which is permanently and inseparably devoted to the business, it would be difficult if not impossible to find its value except through the value of the business. But this does not apply to migratory cars or to the wagons, horses and pouches owned by the express companies in Ohio. With respect to such property it is readily apparent that a tax on the value of the property as a going concern is a tax on the business. This conclusion is fortified rather than disguised by resort to the notion that what the state is taxing is "intangible property." Intangible property has a familiar connotation which is quite distinct from the enjoyment or anticipation of business profits.

The logical nebule which the opinions have exhaled by insisting that taxes on business were taxes on something else was by no means inevitable. It must be dispelled before we can see clearly. It is a legal doctrine that a state cannot tax interstate business, but it is not on economic fact. We might have been saved from wearisome confusion if the court had long ago declared that under some circumstances and by some methods a state may tax interstate business, 4 See note 76, supra.

and that under other circumstances and by other methods it may not. Such a declaration would have turned attention more directly to the circumstances and to the methods. The rules of law might then have been worked out on matter-of-fact lines which avoided logical inconsistency by avoiding fictions and the semblance of generality when the generality was shadow and not substance.

We have already considered the reasons why it is as wise and necessary to allow the states to tax interstate commerce as to allow them to tax property employed in interstate commerce.95 Exemption of such commerce from burdens which local commerce must bear would be equivalent to a bounty on interstate commerce. The withholding of such a bounty from interstate commerce ought not in wisdom to be regarded as "a regulation of it in a constitutional sense." But the court must be zealous to restrain the states. from obtaining revenue from extraterritorial sources or from imposing cumulative exactions on interstate business without similarly burdening all local business. Owing to the ubiquity of property taxation and to the fact that the value of real estate and of stocks and bonds and similar obligations bears a close relation to the income from such property, a state "is less likely to attempt to or effect injurious regulation," when it "is trying simply to value property" than "when it is aiming directly at the receipts from interstate commerce.' On the other hand, the states have been more sporadic and selective in their impositions on occupations and on income. They must therefore be held to strict account when they tax income from interstate commerce. They must establish that the burden is a general and not a discriminatory one.

996

The court is satisfied when the state shows that the income is taken as a fair measure of the value of property assessed for taxation, or when a tax on income is in substitution for a tax on property. It was satisfied in the Ficklen case when gross receipts were taxed in the absence of taxation on property because there was no property to tax. It has been satisfied more recently with a state-wide income tax measured by net rather than gross receipts.97 In the presence of

85 32 HARV. L. REV. 260-62.

96 From Mr. Justice Holmes' opinion in the Galveston case, quoted on page 394, supra.

97 United States Glue Co. v. Oak Creek, 247 U. S. 321, 38 Sup. Ct. Rep. 499 (1918). See pages 415-16, infra.

« PreviousContinue »