Page images
PDF
EPUB

PART 2

SOCIAL SECURITY: A SOUND AND DURABLE
INSTITUTION OF GREAT VALUE 10

Nearly every American has a personal stake in the social security system. Many millions rely on it to safeguard themselves and their families against economic catastrophe when earnings stop because of old age, disability, or death. Attacks on the system designed to create doubts of its soundness and durability are a disservice to the Nation. Several elements of the system, to be sure-the level of benefits, for example, the test of retirement, the benefit rights accorded to women, the adequacy and equity of financing are quite properly subjects of continuing public debate. Social security has not been and should not be a static structure, for it best serves its purpose if it is adapted to changing times and changing conditions. Public discussion addressed to improvement of the system is both necessary and helpful. But discussion of that kind is very different from assertions that the system is basically unsound, that it is bankrupt, or for some other reason doomed to collapse, or that it is a deception foisted on the American public. Charges similar to these have recurrently been made in the past, and as often have been found baseless. They have no more foundation now than they had when first made nearly forty years ago.

Social Security has been probably the most thoroughly and continuously studied, both within and outside government circles, of any program ever enacted by Congress. On five occasions, from 1938 to 1971, the system has been exhaustively reviewed by advisory councils established under congressional auspices and composed of economists and other social scientists and leaders of labor and business, including distinguished actuaries and leaders of the insurance industry. In ach instance, the integrity of the system has been vigorously reaffirmed. This history, if it does nothing more, should foster a healthy Skepticism toward the current destructive attacks.

The conclusions of these councils have carried much weight and have been an influential factor in bringing about the improvements that have been made in the system over the years. The current statutory advisory council will soon issue a report. Like its predecessors, it has a broad assignment-to review the entire social security program and advise how to make it best serve the public interest. We may well await the recommendations of this council and ensuing congressional hearings on substantive changes in the system which are being widely debated. But we should not wait to deal with irresponsible attacks on he soundness of the structure.

THE ASSURANCE OF FUTURE BENEFIT PAYMENTS

The most vicious of these attacks is the one charging that promised social security benefits may not be paid when they fall due twenty or

White Paper issued on February 10, 1975, endorsed by five former Health, Education, and Welfare Secretaries and three former Social Security Commissioners. See appendix 2, 10 for news release giving additional details.

thirty or forty years hence. To the worker who is compelled to contribute from his earnings every payday, who is counting on these benefits for his security in retirement and for the protection of his family in the meantime, planting seeds of unwarranted doubt is a cruelty. What are the facts?

The first fact is that the payment of benefits is mandated by the law of the land. A claim to social security benefits is a legal right enforceable in court, and many claims are in fact so enforced when eligibility is unclear. However one may define a "legal right", it certainly embraces a payment commanded by law and judicially enforceable. The second fact is that Congress has gone far-probably as far as any Congress can go in binding its successors-to assure that future legislators will not, by changing the law, weaken the obligation to pay these benefits. By earmarking the proceeds of social security taxes for the payment of benefits and depositing them in a trust fund for this purpose, by entitling the system insurance, by continuing actions to assure its financial soundness, and by innumerable pronouncements of congressional committees and individual spokesmen, Congress has made clear beyond question its pledge to the American people that the social security commitment will be honored.

The social security system is, in effect, a compact between the people of the United States and their government. Congress, it is true, retains the legal power to violate this compact, which would be a highly irresponsible act, altogether inconsistent with the Congress's 40-year record of responsible action on social security. If there are doubters among us, they should be reminded that a member of Congress who hopes for reelection will not vote to repudiate a promise to virtually his entire constituency. It is inconceivable that a majority of the members of each House of Congress will ever do so.

THE NATURE OF THE CONGRESSIONAL COMMITMENT TO CONTRIBUTORS

The social security commitment differs in an important respect from that of a private insurance company, which in writing a policy fixes its terms in every detail for the life of the policy. Congress, by contrast. has of necessity built an element of flexibility into the national social insurance system. Thus, when Congress has amended the law to improve the benefit structure it has generally given the advantage of the change to those already on the benefit rolls as well as to those who are still contributing. Occasionally, improvement of the structure involves substitution of one benefit for another, as when a provision in the original Act for refund of certain contributions was replaced by the far more valuable provision of dependents' and survivors benefits. One cannot say that under no circumstances will any individual in this massive system suffer some loss in some future contingency as a result of overall improvements in the system. Such adjustments must, of necessity, fall within the range of flexibility that has been reserved to Congress. What one can say with confidence is that the congressional sense of fair play, reflecting that of the public, gives assurance that

SOCIAL SECURITY IS PROPERLY DESCRIBED AS INSURANCE

It is occasionally asserted that social security is not in fact insurance, that so describing it is misleading, and that its trust funds are grossly inadequate. These assertions have been used by some to foster doubt that the promised benefits will be paid. All these assertions are unfounded.

Although the propriety of its use is a semantic question, the term "insurance" is not without significance to either the congressional or the public perception of social security. Social insurance is a concept long and well recognized across the world, and is one into which social security fits neatly. For good reasons, social insurance differs in important respects from private insurance, but it embodies the central element of financial protection against defined hazards, through a pooling of contributions and a sharing of risks, with benefits payable as a matter of legal right on the happening of stated events. It is fallacious to argue, as some persons do, that the workers' payments are not insurance contributions because they are taxes-all taxes are compulsory contributions, either for the general support of government or for some particular governmental activity, and these payments are nonetheless contributions to an insurance system because they are also taxes. Congress used the word "insurance" in the statute as one indication of the character of the commitment it was undertaking, and the Supreme Court of the United States has stated that the term "social insurance" accurately describes the program. While anyone has the privilege of dissent, the Court's approval should have put an end to charges that the nomenclature is deceptive.

THE ADEQUACY AND INTEGRITY OF THE TRUST FUNDS

The matter of reserves has been a topic of confused debate almost since the ink dried on the original enactment of social security. In the early days it was said that the contemplated "reserve account" would be unmanageably large; now it is being charged that the social security trust funds are far too small. It was also said in 1936, and is occasionally even said today, that the funds are fictitious because they are invested in government bonds. Charges that social security reserves have been grossly inadequate and charges that they are fictitious have been emphatically rejected by every one of the advisory councils, and they were rejected unanimously as early as 1945 by the social Security committee of the insurance industry. A government insurance ystem which has its future income assured by the taxing power has no need to build up large funds that a private insurer would require if it underwrote similar liabilities, and indeed, it would be unwise to the point of irresponsibility to accumulate such sums. The only need for a trust fund is as a contingency reserve large enough to tide the system over any temporary change in income and outgo; if an increase in revenues should be necessary, the trust fund would enable Congress to delay such action during a period of economic recession. As for the worth of the assets in the funds, one need only consider that if a private trustee held these government bonds they would be gilt-edged securities, and then ask oneself how their value disappears when the same.

The funds reflect the fact that, now, with a substantially mature system, annual contribution income and annual outgo are roughly in balance. This is another way of saying what critics harp on as though it were a demerit, that the benefits paid this year to the aged, the disabled and their dependents, and to survivors of the deceased derive in the main from this year's contributions by workers and their employers. As long as his benefits are adequately assured by the government's ability to obtain future income, today's young worker need have no concern because his contributions are used to pay today's beneficiaries, or because his future benefits will be paid from future contributions.

OFT-REFUTED CHARGES

The charges thus far considered are, in their main outlines, repetition of earlier efforts to discredit the social security program, and they are no more valid now than they have been in the past. Repeatedly and consistently, Congress, after extended study by its responsible committees as well as the distinguished advisory councils, has found these charges to be without merit.

Other charges, though not new in themselves, have acquired a new emphasis because of the steady rise over recent years in the contribution rate and in the ceiling on taxable earnings, and these charges deserve consideration. The increase in the amount of contributions, of course, must be heavily discounted if one thinks in terms of purchasing power rather than of dollars, and in terms of the increase in personal incomes. But whatever the value of the dollar, providing a decent measure of economic security to the retired, to the disabled, and to widows and orphans is a hugely expensive undertaking. The questions that demand serious thought relate not so much to the total sum which the system raises by taxation as they do to the manner in which the burden is distributed.

THE SOCIAL SECURITY SYSTEM IS NOT REGRESSIVE

It is said, for one thing, that social security taxes are regressive because the wealthy pay smaller percentages of their earned income than do the poor, in contrast to the general income tax, under which the wealthy pay higher percentages. If social security collections were taxes for general support of the government, this charge would be unanswerable; one can hardly imagine that Congress would ever have imposed these levies, or would now allow them to remain on the statute books, except as a part of a social insurance system. This charge illustrates, indeed, the fallacy of looking at the two parts of social security in isolation from each other, an approach which inevitably distorts the issues and loads the argument. The issue here is not whether social security taxes are regressive but whether the social security system, taking into account both benefits and contributions, is open to this charge. The answer to that question is "no." The benefit formula is so designed as to give a larger return for each dollar of contributions to the low-wage earner than to the high. While there are other factors to be considered, some favoring the poor and some working against them, the net effect of the system is to transfer some income from the more affluent as a group to the less affluent. It is legitimate to argue

that the system ought to be made more progressive than it is, as for instance by the introduction of a government contribution derived from general revenues, but it is not legitimate to argue, by disregarding the benefit payments, that the system as now structured is regressive.

Another contention which has gained in prominence with the increasing amount of contributions is that, regardless of the liberality of future returns, the present burden is simply more than people in low- and moderate-income brackets ought to bear out of current earnings. It is often pointed out that many of these people pay more in social security than in income taxes, though the significance of this comparison is not apparent. Many persons pay more for any number of things than they pay in income taxes, and there is nothing inherently inequitable in charging them more for the protections afforded by social security than they are charged for the general support of government. No one can be dogmatic about what burdens on various income groups are tolerable, or represent good social policy, but to say that the poor are too heavily taxed for social security is to say either that their protection should be reduced or that it should be more largely subsidized by the wealthier segments of society. Not many argue for the former alternative, but the latter is widely and properly a matter of debate.

SOCIAL SECURITY GIVES CONTRIBUTORS A GOOD BARGAIN

Statements have been broadly disseminated that social security gives the contributor a poor bargain, and that he could do far better by investing the amount of his contributions in the private markets. This is not true. If we exclude speculative investments (including investment in the erstwhile "ever-rising stock market"), which can always yield some individual a windfall but can also yield a terrible loss, the individual under the social security system receives better value from the government than he could obtain elsewhere. With the automatic escalation of workers' benefit rights as wages rise, and the automatic cost-of-living increase for those already on the benefit rolls, there is no question at all that the worker receives protection worth more than his total contributions with interest. This is true even if all or most of the employer contribution is assumed to rest on the employee in final incidence (either in the form of lower wages or in terms of higher prices to him as a consumer). As long as protection for current workers is kept up to date via automatic escalation provisions there is no way for the social security contributor to get better protection for his or her money.

IMPROVING SOCIAL SECURITY FINANCING

Congress keeps a watchful eye on the actuarial balance of the social security system. It has sought, so far as knowledge available at any given time makes possible, to assure the system of adequate financing both for the short run and for the long run. Thus on the basis of all the information available at the time of the most recent amendments, it was thought that the system was adequately financed within a reasonable range for such estimates.

« PreviousContinue »