Page images
PDF
EPUB

SE

ve

care in the hospital, and to deny hospital staff privileges to applicants who have shown evidence of poor quality elsewhere. Such decisions to suspend or deny practice credentials can be quite controversial, and lead to litigation on a variety of fronts.

pez

appear to be influenced by the facts of the individual case, rather than the specific structure of the state immunity laws.89 Concerns about the confidentiality of peer review will likely continue to be an area of active litigation in the 1990s, especially as more states pass laws encouraging organizational peer review and quality assurance activities, and require that some of this data be turned over to the state for regulatory purposes. 90

[merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small]

First, physicians who have suffered suspension of credentials may claim that their due process rights were not respected, especially in cases involving public hospitals.84 Alternatively, physicians may seek rights of cross examination and other trappings of adjudicative process.85 More importantly, physicians who lose their practice privileges may allege antitrust violations: the aggrieved physician will claim that the decision to suspend privileges was not motivated by concerns about quality of care, but rather was an attempt to curb competition in the specialty area. 86 Indeed peer review activities are now drawing considerable antitrust scrutiny, a trend that will likely accelerate in light of a recent Supreme Court decision.87 Yet another concern of physicians who serve on peer review committees is the threat of involvement in malpractice litigation. Since these committees often pass judgment on specific incidents involving physicians on the medical staff, their activities are of special interest to plaintiffs' attorneys who would like access to peer review committee documents. While most states provide explicit immunity for peer review activities, some state courts have managed to find exceptions to these statutes in order to allow discovery of the peer review data. 88 Such judicial decisions

These various types of litigation create serious concerns on the part of physicians involved in peer review. Even those physicians who recognize that the best long-term response to malpractice litigation is better quality medical practice, and that a physician's peers are better judges of medical care than lawyers or juries, are hesitant to become involved in peer review activities that may lead to litigation. While this is and will continue to be a significant problem even in the present system of tort litigation, it would become even more prominent if one moved to general organizational liability of hospitals. Thus, any comprehensive effort to address medical malpractice litiga. tion must also address the legal problems raised by peer review activities.

[ocr errors][ocr errors][ocr errors][merged small][ocr errors][ocr errors][ocr errors][ocr errors]

v.

[ocr errors]

No-Fault Patient Compensation-The drawbacks of both traditional tort litigation and of those alternatives that still rely on determinations of fault have led a number of people to advocate “no fault” approaches to medical injury compensation. As far back as the early 1970s, a number of scholars were proposing partial or complete no-fault systems.91 The partial no fault approaches center on accelerated compensation for designated injuries that are quite likely to be avoidable.92 These particular injuries would be extracted from the tort regime and be compensated administratively. Medical adversity insurance differs from pure no-fault or social insurance in that the providers of care remain responsible for paying for the listed outcomesma form of "strict liability" through provider-purchased, experience-rated casualty insurance. More recently, proponents have been able to draw on the experience of New Zealand os and

[ocr errors][ocr errors][ocr errors]

84 See Richardson St. Johns Mercy Hospital, 674 S.W.2d 200 (Mo.App.1984).

86 See Rao v. St. Elizabeth's Hospital, 488 N.E.2d 685 (III. App. 5 Dist. 1986).

86 It seems likely that there will be more antitrust litigation in the future. Since 1975, with the decision of Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U.S. 773 (1975), the Supreme Court has indicated that the practice of the learned professions will be considered commerce, and thus subject to the scrutiny of the antitrust laws. The initial Supreme Court cases regarding health care antitrust concerned efforts to remove anticompetitive rules which had been put in place by insurers and providers. See Union Labor Life Insurance Company v. Pireno, 458 U.S. 119 (1981); Arizono v. Maricopa County Medical Society, 457 U.S. 332 (1981). Soon however, aggrieved individuals began to request antitrust scrutiny regarding the behavior of individual hospitals or physicians. See Jefferson Parish Hospital District #2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2 (1984); Weiss v. York Hospital, 745 F.2d 786 (3rd Cir. 1984).

87 See Patrick v. Burget, 108 S.Ct. 1658 (1988). With the decision of Patrick v. Burget, the Supreme Court indicated that the state action doctrine would not immunize state-required peer review activities by private hospital staffs from antitrust litigation unless states provided official review of such private decisions. Although the Health Care Quality Improvement Act of 1986 was intended to limit antitrust litigation regarding peer review, many observers doubt that it will have this effect. See e.g. Colantonio, “The Health Care Quality Improvement Act of 1986 and its Impact on Hospital Law,” West Virginia Law Review 91 (1988): 91; Blumstein and Sloan, “Antitrust in Hospital Peer Review," Law and Contemporary Problems 31 (1988): 7. Thus we can expect continued antitrust scrutiny of peer review activities. See Bolt v. Halifor Hospital Medical Center, 851 F.2d 1273 (11th Circuit), vacated and petition for rehearing en banc granted, 861 F.2d 1233 (11th Cir. 1988), reinstated in part and vacated in part en banc, 874 F.2d 755 (11th Cir. 1989). Lawyers have had some doubts about bringing antitrust suits in this area, and since the major Supreme Court decision is so recent, it is difficult to predict the amount of litigation that will occur in the future. Nonetheless, the Patrick decision can only serve as a litigation incentive.

os See Kalish v. M. Sinai Hospital, 270 N.W. 2d 783 (Minn. 1978).

89 Compare Coburn v. Seda, 677 P.2d 173 (1984), with Chandra v. Sprinkle, 678 S.W.2d 804 (Mo. 1984).

90 See e.g. Beth Israel Hospital Association v. The Board of Registration in Medicine, 515 N.E.2d 574 (Mass. 1987).

91 See Havighurst and Tancredi, "Medical Adversity Insurance, a No Fault to Medical Malpractice and Quality Assurance," Insurance Low Journal 613 (1974): 69; O'Connell, “No-Fault Insurance for Injuries Arising from Medical Treatment: A Proposal for Elective coverage," Emory Law Journal 24 (1975): 21.

»? See Tancredi, “Designing a No-Fault Alternative," Law and Contempo rary Problems 49 (1986): 277; American Bar Association, Designated Compex sable Event System: A Feasibility Study (1979). The latest iteration of the concept is the ACE (accelerated compensable event).

See Gellhorn, “Medical Malpractice Litigation (U.S.).—Medical Mishap Compensation (N.Z.)," Cornell Law Review 73 (1988): 170.

[blocks in formation]

would do away with the deterrent effect of medical malpractice litigation. This contention, however, overlooks the fact that no-fault is still a mode of legal liability with one party required to compensate the victims of its activities, and the requisite insurance would likely be provided at the level of hospital or other health care organization where premiums could be strongly experience rated. 102

[ocr errors]

Recently, we have completed a study of medical injury, and the costs arising out of such injury, in the state of New York. The data from this study indicate that in New York, at least, one can provide full compensation for the net financial losses of all seriously injured patients for roughly the same amount expended on litigation for only a selected number of those negligently injured. 103

care

How does a no-fault system work for compensation of medical injury? In Sweden, a combine of insurance companies provides a no-fault insurance program.98

Complementing, yet separate from, the insurance archive

compensation plan is the Medical Responsibility Board (MRB) that hears complaints about quality of care rendered to individuals.99 The advantage of uncoupling the compensation and deterrent approaches to medical injuries as the Swedes have done is that it frees both functions from the adversarial notions of

tort litigation, providing greater and more equitable _c2017 compensation and stronger deterrence signals. 100 stigatii

Nonetheless, there are significant problems with the Timo no-fault approach. Many have argued that our major subok present-day use of no-fault within workers' compensa

tion has failed to provide appropriate compensation for individuals suffering from occupational dis

Still others fear that a no-fault approach

[ocr errors]
[ocr errors]

101 eases.

Social Insurance—The relationship between providing health insurance for all Americans and tort reform must be underlined, because comprehensive health benefits would deal directly with many of the patient losses for which malpractice litigation now seeks redress. One major advantage of the Swedish and New Zealand systems for no-fault insurance for medical injury is that these compensation systems are nestled within a much more encompassing safety net of social welfare programs. For instance, in Sweden, there is a national health system that provides medical care for all individuals and comprehensive disability insurance for lost earnings. Thus their no-fault system does not absorb much of the costs arising out of an iatrogenic injury, and the smaller stake in the outcome reduces the intensity of conflict in individual cases.

7 of the

[ocr errors]
[ocr errors]
[ocr errors]

e quief njURS

and it sity

Broader disability insurance and sick leave benefits would also decrease the overall costs associated with compensation programs for iatrogenic injury. When a collateral source offset is in place, any increase in the coverage of first party loss insurance correspondingly reduces the losses left to be handled by the much more expensive system of third party malpractice insurance.

INCIT

Tk3

" See Rosenthal, Dealing With Medical Malpractice: The British and Swedish Experience, (1988) 131-206.

os See Halley, Fowks, Bigler, Ryan, Medical Malpractice Solutions: Systems and Proposals for Injury Compensation (Springfield, III., Charles Thomas 1989).

96 See British Medical Association, No-Fault Compensation Working Party Report (1987); R. Prichard, Medical Malpractice (1989).

97 See White, “Innovative No-Fault Tort Reform for an Endangered Spens." | cialty,” Virginia Law Review 74 (1988): 1487. Some have criticized the

Virginia system for only controlling cases of people who would probably recover in the tort system, thereby resulting in less compensation for them and no more compensation for others. See Gallup, "Can No-Fault Compensation of Impaired Infants Alleviate the Malpractice Crisis in Obstetrics?Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law, 14 (1989): 69.

*8 A patient seeking compensation for medical injury must merely show that her injuries are of a designated type and compensation is available. There need be no allegation of negligence, and thus physicians often assist their patients in the effort to secure compensation. See Oldertz, “The Swedish Patient Insurance Scheme-Eight Years of Experience,” Medical Legal Journal 52 (1984): 43.

" Most such complaints are brought by patients but physicians are encouraged to self-report to their department heads who in return report to the MRB. The MRB can discipline physicians who provide poor quality care or can decide that no action is necessary. The MRB has both expert input and political and citizen representatives, similar to the boards envisioned by the AMA's fault-based system.

100 Patient compensation is more straightforward in the absence of the corrective justice aspects of tort litigation. Physicians can actually assist patients in their efforts to receive compensation. On the other hand, since compensation is not directly sought from the physician or his insurer, data regarding sub-standard care is more freely available. Quality assurance efforts proceed smoothly, free from concerns about investigations by plaintiffs attorneys regarding the quality assurance data. Thus, at least in theory, a no-fault system would provide greater compensation and clearer deterrent signals.

To See Barth and Hunt, Workers Compensation and Work-Related Illnesses and Diseases (1980): see also Kutchins, The Most Exclusive Remedy is No Remedy At All: Workers Compensation Coverage for Occupational Diseases," Labor Law Journal 32 (1981): 219-20. Indeed, one might conjecture that determining causation in medical injury cases may be much more difficult than determining causation in workers' compensation cases in that most patients will have a significant background of disease from which the medical care-induced injury must be disentangled. Thus no-fault approaches to medical injuries will likely have inherently higher administrative costs than

[ocr errors]

fatal 19

[ocr errors]

Beyond Health Care Providers-Malpractice litigation is not the only aspect of tort law that plays a major role in the health care area. Just as prominent and often just as troubling are product liability suits against manufacturers of vaccines, prescription drugs and other medical appliances. Indeed, many of these cases are the result of the combined action of a manu

[ocr errors][ocr errors][ocr errors][merged small][ocr errors][ocr errors]

102 The best work on workers' compensation and deterrence suggests that workers' compensation has a considerable preventive effect on workplace fatalities. See Viscusi and Moore, Compensation Mechanisms for Job Risks: Wages, Workers' Compensation and Product Liability (forthcoming, Princeton University Press).

103 See Harvard Medical Practice Study, Patients, Doctors, and Lawyers (1990), chap. 8.

workers' compensation.

the event itience 8/10

CONCLUSION

facturer which designs and markets the drug and a physician--the learned intermediary-who prescribes the drug for a patient. 104 Thus, any effort to cut back sharply on the tort liability of the doctor is likely to redirect the pressure by the victim for tort relief towards the manufacturer (as has recently been evident in the rise of third party product suits by employees covered by no-fault workers' compensation). Because drug manufacturers do operate within a national market, the federal government must be especially sensitive to the possible impact of measures directed at doctors and patients alone. 105 This is not to imply that there is no legitimate federal responsibility for malpractice law itself. As the largest third party purchaser of health care, the federal government must be concerned about the impact of tort litigation on the costs and quality of that care. In addition, the federal government must be sensitive to the way its own legal policies (e.g., antitrust) interact with and occasionally obstruct the efforts by individual states to im

[ocr errors]

clude

desige

[ocr errors]

health

The

We have reviewed a broad array of issues posed by malpractice litigation for the health care system. In the mid-70's and in the mid-80's, providers in many regions of the country felt grave concern about spiralling liability costs. Although much of the hue and cry has died down now that premium levels have plateaued, the empirical research we reviewed earlier shows there is ample room for another upsurge in the 90's in malpractice claims and premiums.

As In the interim, a host of policy changes have been

infor proposed and adopted within each of the health care, legal, and insurance systems whose interplay generates the observed rates of patient injuries, tort claims, and premium costs. We were asked to provide here a need review of the arguments for and against these various ideas, not to spell out and to defend our own favored additic proposals. As we have tried to indicate, though, there are no easy solutions to this complex set of problems: indeed, apparently desirable changes in one area of the law (e.g., antitrust) may run counter to equally benefit appealing initiatives taken elsewhere (e.g., quality as

n this surance through peer review). Too often conventional

health tort reform has reflected a rather narrow view not just of the actual source of the problems posed by malpractice litigation for doctors, but also of the need for some such liability mechanism to insure safe care for patients. Recently, some systematic empirical and analytical work has begun to emerge about more fundamental possibilities--e.g., the AMA's administrative

ned by fault proposal and the New York state study of the incidence, compensation, and prevention of patient injuries. At this point of time, then, it would be premature to endorse specific proposals for statutory change, especially for enactment at the national level. What is needed, instead, is careful analysis of the growing body of data now available, and the design, implementation, and evaluation of demonstration projects. We would hope that this Commission, whose primary focus is the availability and affordability of medical care, would recommend that a similarly

in systematic inquiry be mounted about the ways which malpractice litigation or its alternatives can best enhance the quality of the medical care thereby the provided

[ocr errors]

atheld

The

[ocr errors]
[ocr errors]

prove the situation. 106

104 See Shulman, "The Broader Message of Acutane," American Journal of Public Health 79 (1989): 1565-1570. For a recent, revealing illustration of this phenomenon, see O'Gilvie v. International Playtex, Inc., 821 F. 2d. 1438 (10th Cir. 1987), where a doctor's misdiagnosis of toxic shock syndrome precipitated an $11.5 million jury verdict against the product manufacturer, including $10 million in punitive damages.

106 In Sweden, the institution of a no-fault insurance approach to medical injury was wedded to a no-fault program for compensation for drug related injuries, a program which is underwritten by drug companies. See Rosenthal, Dealing With Medical Malpractice: The British and Swedish Experience. In this country, no-fault system for vaccine related injury has recently been insti'uted by the United States Congress. Vaccines represent one of the two exeptions to the learned intermediary rule and thus vaccine manufacturers nust provide patients with a warning concerning the risks associated with vaccination. See Reyes v. Wyeth Laboratories, 498 F.2d 1264 (5th Cir. 1973), cert. denied, 419 U.S. 1096 (1974). At least partially as a result of this requirement regarding warning, vaccine manufacturers have faced a great deal of product liability litigation arising out of parties injured by vaccines. See Institute of Medicine, Vaccine Supply and Innovation (1985).

In response, Congress passed an amendment to Title III of the Omnibus Health Legislation which was known as the National Childhood Vaccine Injury Act. See S.1744, 99th Cong., 2d sess. (1986). The Act creates a mandatory no-fault compensation scheme for individuals injured by childhood vaccines. An injured party may either accept compensation awarded through the no-fault proceeding or bring a separate civil suit, but in the latter circumstance, theories of liabilities are significantly limited. Under the no-fault scheme, burden of proofs are lower, as is the potential compensation. A trust fund, consisting of an excise tax on dosages of childhood vaccine, provides compensation. See Budget Reconciliation Act of 1987, P.L. 100-203, sec. 4301-07.

Of course, childhood vaccines may be a special case. They are a necessary public health tool but not an area of great profit making by drug companies. Therefore, the industry's threats to absent itself from the marketplace in this particularly important area are likely to bring about Congressional intervention. Other types of drugs might have less of a claim on Congressional attention. Nonetheless, the Vaccine Act demonstrates that tort reform could extend itself to drugs and other products. We await some further maturation of this program so as to evaluate how well it functions.

106 Consider the following example. New York State's Malpractice Reform Bill of 1986 required hospitals to purchase excess coverage for physicians practicing on the staffs of the hospitals. Thus the hospitals had to bear new costs. They passed these costs along to Blue Cross/Blue Shield, commercial insurers, and to the state Medicaid program. However, federal Medi

Instrat

[ocr errors]
[ocr errors]
[ocr errors]
[ocr errors]

care disallowed any reimbursement for these purposes, and the issue is still in litigation. This demonstrates how the prominent federal role in the provisica of medical care creates federal interest in tort reform.

[ocr errors][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][ocr errors]

WHAT ARE THE BENEFIT DESIGN FEATURES OF FEE-FOR-SERVICE HEALTH PLANS?

As you requested, this paper provides background chain information on health plan benefits and a discussion of h of their a standard, or "basic,” health benefit plan. Also in

cluded is a discussion of how health plan benefits are ose into injures et designed to meet certain requirements, such as the

need to cover certain population groups (e.g., the low agains the income) or to conform to certain cost constraints. In end our et addition, the paper presents and discusses several adicate the health benefit plan options.

[ocr errors]
[ocr errors]

The design of a health plan's benefits includes several features that define the benefits and help to determine what the benefits will cost. These benefit features include (1) covered services, (2) limits on allowable charges, (3) limits on services covered or total payments, (4) enrollee cost sharing and catastrophic protection, and (5) cost containment features. Only the first feature, covered services, pertains to the types of health care services covered by a plan; the other features define how the costs of health care services are divided between the plan and the plan enrollees.

The focus of this paper is on fee-for-service plan in comes benefits, which is the most prevalent type of coverage bere left in this country, as opposed to the benefit structure of de oftea or health maintenance organizations. In addition, the dis

cussion focuses only on health benefits for the e polisi nonelderly (under age 65) population.

[ocr errors]

5, but ak : 5m to

Covered and Excluded Health Care Services

The specification of the five health benefit plan optematis a tions was determined in discussions with you. We merge Alte agreed that we would use three plans already develAMAIE oped by the Congressional Research Service (CRS) as me suis illustrative plans for our project on health insurance eventies for the uninsured: a “typical” private employer-based en it was plan, a "tailored" plan designed for the low-income, moral it and a "catastrophic” plan for medical expenses that at at the

care large compared to family income. In addition, you carefu bili requested that we develop (1) a typical plan that inLilable si cludes preventive services and (2) a reduced typical

plan which includes greater enrollee cost sharing and

excludes mental health and dental services, but inilahind cludes preventive services. The relatively lengthy disunty cussion of preventive services responds to your

request for information on these frequently uncovered services,

The major types of health care services that health plans cover include hospital services (inpatient and outpatient), surgical services (inpatient and outpatient), physician services, X-ray and laboratory tests, emergency care, prescription drugs, and mental health care, including substance abuse (inpatient and outpatient). Most employer health plans cover these benefits. What varies more from plan to plan than the types of services covered are the reimbursement levels for each service and the plan's cost containment features.

[ocr errors]

of har thi

[ocr errors]

Other services sometimes covered in health plans include dental care, vision care, well-baby and child care, preventive care including routine physical examinations, home health services, and care in an extended care facility.

or its

e matas

* Pupa at

Report prepared by Janet Lundy, Specialist in Social Legislation, Education and Public Welfare Division, Congressional Research Service, October 24, 1989.

Any costs enrollees incur for services not covered by a health plan ("excluded” services) are neither paid for by the plan nor applied toward the plan's deductible requirements or catastrophic limits (described below). Examples of services and expenses that are

[blocks in formation]

or

not covered under many health insurance plans are cosmetic surgery; infertility services; services not deemed "medically necessary" such as those done for educational, research, or vocational training purposes; experimental treatments; tests treatments not needed for a particular condition; and services that do not meet generally accepted standards of medical practice. Plans may also specify the type of providers to whom payment can be made for covered services and may exclude treatment by others. For example, a plan may pay for mental health services only if provided by a psychiatrist or psychologist.

Enrollee Cost Sharing and Catastrophic Protection

E incle For plans for E LOD Cove

Cost

In recent years, health plans have extended their use of enrollee cost sharing, including deductibles and coinsurance, in an attempt to reduce plan costs. A deductible is a specific dollar amount, commonly $100 to $200, that must be paid by the insured before the health plan will begin paying benefits. Typically, employer plans require the insured to pay a yearly overall plan deductible (also called a "major medical" deductible) prior to plan payment for covered serv. ices. Coinsurance is a specified percentage of each bill for a covered medical services that the insured must pay, commonly 20 percent. The coinsurance is applied to the remaining covered expenses after any de ductible has been met by the insured.

Limits on Allowable Charges

[merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small]

Most health plans use some method for determining the extent to which a medical expense is eligible for payment. These methods are designed to exert some control over plan costs by setting limits on the amount of a health care provider's charges or costs that will be reimbursed. For example, in general, inpatient hospital bills are paid by Medicare under a prospective payment system, by commercial insurers as a percentage of the hospital's average charge for a semiprivate hospital room, or by Blue Cross and Blue Shield according to contract limits negotiated by the hospital and the Blue plan.

Opinio

such a

Many plans include as a benefit a yearly limit (also known as a catastrophic, out-of-pocket, or stop-loss limit) on the amount of cost sharing (coinsurance and sometimes deductibles) that the insured must pay from their own pockets. After that limit (commonly $1,000 to $3,000) is reached, the plan pays 100 percent of any additional expenses for services covered by the plan

. bat ege

duction for com hon C clude

A plan may pay physicians according to a method known as “reasonable and customary” (R&C). Under R&C, payment is made according to the physician's actual charge for a particular service, limited by a maximum determined as a percentage of the average charge for that service by physicians in the same geographic area. Plans may also pay according to a fee schedule, where the plan establishes maximum payment amounts in each geographic area for each service. Blue Cross and Blue Shield plans generally limit payment to physicians by negotiating contracts under which the physician agrees to accept the Blue plan's payment as full payment for covered services.

[merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][ocr errors][ocr errors][ocr errors][merged small][merged small]

Limits on Services Covered or Total Payments

[ocr errors]
[merged small][ocr errors]

Health plans frequently set limits on the units of service (e.g., visits or days of care) covered by the plan, or on the maximum dollar amount paid by the plan per service, per year, or over the insured person's lifetime. For example, a plan's mental health coverage may limit payment for inpatient mental health care to 30 days per year and limit outpatient mental health care to a maximum number of visits per

Studies such as the Rand Health Insurance Expenment (HIE) have found that enrollee cost sharing can lead to lower utilization and lower health plan costs The HIE found that per capita expenses for enrollees in a plan with a 95 percent coinsurance rate (i.., the

percentage paid by the insured) for outpatient services

« PreviousContinue »