Page images
PDF
EPUB

Federal subsidy of the REA program. On the contrary, these proposals would tend to increase the scope and magnitude of tax-exempt electric operations, replacing or displacing taxpaying electric systems with which they are in competition and thereby proportionately reducing Federal revenues. Furthermore, these proposals would free these Federally subsidized, tax-exempt electric systems from any meaningful control by Congress and other regulatory bodies even though they would remain heavily subsidized by the Federal Government.

We respectfully suggest that no emergency exists which would justify precipitous action by this Committee. Congress has appropriated entirely adequate funds ($375,000,000) for REA loans in the coming fiscal year. S. 3337 and S. 3720, as proposed, is legislation of far-reaching import which is deserving of careful and deliberate study by all affected parties.

Thank you for the privilege of appearing before you to present our views with regard to this extremely important proposed legislation.

HOUSTON, TEX., August 31, 1966.

Hon. HERMAN E. TALMADGE,
Chairman, Agricultural Credit and Rural Electrification Subcommittee, Com-
mittee on Agriculture and Forestry, U.S. Senate, Room 324, Old Senate Office
Building, Washington, D.C.

DEAR SENATOR TALMADGE: It is our understanding that your Subcommittee's hearings on subject bills were concluded on August 19, 1966, that the record of such hearings has been held open until September 2, 1966 to incorporate additional statements by interested persons and that no further hearings on these or similar bills are scheduled by your Subcommittee.

In the event additional hearings should be scheduled on these or similar "electric bank" bills we will appreciate an opportunity to appear before your Subcommittee and be heard concerning such bills.

We are attaching a copy of the statement concerning the "electric bank" bills which we filed with the House Agriculture Committee in our letter of May 31, 1966 concerning H.R. 14837 (Cooley) and H.R. 14000 (Poage). It appears that subject S. 3720 is identical with the Committee Print No. 2 version of H.R. 14837 (except that S. 3720 would fix a 3% instead of a 4% maximum limit on intermediate bank loans) and that our general statements in the House are equally applicable to subject bills.

We feel that the subjects of discriminatory taxation and control by Congress are of crucial importance in this controversy and that they deserve far more attention than many of the mechanical details which have been the subject of much discussion.

We will appreciate it, therefore, if you will have this letter and the attached letter filed as a part of the record of your Subcommittee's hearings on subject bills, as a general and preliminary statement on our part concerning subject bills. As noted above, we will appreciate an opportunity to update and amplify our comments in person if your Subcommittee decides to take up this general subject again.

Respectfully yours,

HOUSTON LIGHTING & POWER CO., By P. H. ROBINSON, President.

HOUSTON, TEX., May 31, 1966.

Hon. HAROLD D. COOLEY,

Chairman, Agriculture Committee,

House of Representatives,

Washington, D.C.

DEAR MR. CHAIRMAN: We appreciate this opportunity to submit our views on subject bills in connection with the hearings beginning today.

THE PROPOSED REA "BANK" PLANS

What is the REA program? How do the "bank" proposals relate to this program? These are difficult questions because of the fundamental ambivalence of the program as it is presently administered:

At its best the REA program has brought needed electric service to rural areas which probably would not have obtained it any other way.

At its worst the REA program, with no further unserved rural areas to be served, has turned its no-longer-needed aggressiveness in the direction of displacing and destroying existing suppliers of electricity.

The danger presented by the "bank" proposals is that they aid in accomplishing the worst and are not necessary to the accomplishment of the best.

TOOLS (SOMETIMES WEAPONS) EMPLOYED

There were only two tools which Congress found it necessary to employ to enable the REA co-ops to perform at their best in the legitimate sphere of their rural electrification objective-tax shelter and subsidized interest rates. In recent years these same two tools have been turned by the REA into weapons to enable them to succeed in performing at their worst in the sphere of illegitimate activities unrelated to the serving of unserved rural areas.

The tools, both important, are not of equal seriousness from the standpoint of potential danger, however:

Interest subsidies.-Much is heard about one of these two tools-the subsidized interest rate-and it is so thoroughly understood that it will not be labored here. It is by far the less dangerous of the two weapons.

Tax shelter. As to the other weapon, however, the tax shelter, there is a general lack of understanding. We will develop this subject in some detail because we believe an understanding of it is essential to an understanding of the over-all problem created by REA in the United States economy of 1966. The discriminatory taxation which results when the REA co-ops enter the takeover phase is economically crucial and decisive where it is allowed to persist.

CONTROL

So much for the REA's legitimate and illegitimate aims and the tools used to accomplish both.

The main subject of this letter is Control-control by Congress of this program which it created and which it has supervised and kept supplied with funds now for thirty years. The control which has been exercised by Congress annually, as it considered REA's requests for appropriations, has been the only control which has been or can be exerted to keep the co-ops within their legitimate sphere and out of their illegitimate sphere. It is the only control which can keep REA within the limits of its rural electrification function and prevent it from embarking on further extensions of its efforts, in no wise related to rural electrification, to displace and destroy tax-paying industry.

It is the elimination of this control by Congress that is sought by all the present REA “bank" bills. Such bills all, in one way or another, seek to throw off the supervising and restraining hand of Congress. Moreover, the effect of

such bills would be to eliminate all Congressional surveillance and scrutiny. If the REA proponents are able to carry out this legislative coup they will have created an autonomous, self-perpetuating monster which will be in an enviable position with respect to the three key elements of the problem:

1. Tax shelter weapon-unaffected.

2. Interest subsidy weapon-restricted slightly but relatively unimportant anyway.

3. Congressional control-eliminated.

It is in this context that the elimination of Congressional control-whether under the guise of an REA "bank" bill or otherwise becomes so important. We recognize, however, that the reader of this letter might not understand or agree with us that it is important and might have a number of fair questions to ask. We will anticipate several of these questions and attempt to answer them ahead of time:

Question No. 1

Why do you say that the tax shelter weapon is so important-isn't the reason for the difference the fact that the co-ops are nonprofit associations?

The answer to this question can become very complicated but it need not be. In the first place, the tax-paying industries with which the co-ops "compete" do not really pay taxes themselves. Their profits (or "returns"), as public utilities, are fixed after taxes so that all taxes, like other "cost-of-service" items, are actually paid by the customer. This may be easily seen by assuming different Federal income tax rates-the allowable profit or return of a utility would be unaffected but the customers' rates would be changed up or down to reflect the difference. An idea of the quantum of the difference between what the taxpaying investor-owned companies must collect from their customers for such purpose and what the co-ops must collect from their customers may be seen from the comparison on the next page:

The chart below shows the comparisons of the relative "overburden" for taxes and interest as between all the cooperatives in the United States and the seven major investor-owned utilities in Texas, both for 1964. (For details see Exhibit A attached.)

[graphic][subsumed][subsumed][subsumed][subsumed][subsumed][subsumed][subsumed][subsumed][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small]

(**MECHANICAL COST, AS USED HEREIN, MEANS ALL COSTS OTHER THAN TAXES AND INTEREST)

In the second place, the idea that a co-op is a nonprofit association of farmers is properly applicable only to those co-ops which have remained in the legitimate sphere of rural electrification activities. Such a contention is a travesty when it is applied to a co-op that is aggressively seeking to take industrial plants and defense installations away from existing electric suppliers.

The bar chart above represents not only the decisive economic nature of the tax shelter, from a customer's standpoint (because he must pay it), but also the relative unimportance of the interest subsidy.

Question No. 2

Why is Congress' control so essential? Can't the people who are hurt by the illegitimate activities of the REA go into court and prevent them?

The answer to this question has been long and consistently announced by the courts: the tax-paying industry which is being destroyed by the REA's illegitimate activities has no "standing to sue"-it must seek redress, if any, in the halls of Congress.

Question No. 3

Isn't the real purpose of the REA "bank" to allow the co-ops to borrow more money to build more lines as needed in rural areas?

The answer to this question lies in the understanding of "G & T's". Generating and transmission co-ops, the so-called G & T's, and generating plants and transmission lines built by ordinary, theretofore purely distribution co-ops, have been the battlegrounds over which the issue of control by Congress has been fought in recent years. Almost without exception the generating plants and transmission lines are unneeded, duplicative of existing facilities and wasteful

of public money in addition to the eventual elimination of tax-paying industry that results.

If Congress were to refuse to allow the construction of further such G & T's there would be absolutely no need for any "banks"-additional lines in rural areas could be easily taken care of under existing laws.

Question No. 4

Isn't electric industry opposition to co-ops simply an effort to prevent competition?

The bar chart above (on page 5) furnishes the answer to this question with little comment being necessary. A co-op, having to collect only 12 cents for taxes and interest from its customers for each one dollar of mechanical costs, can hardly be spoken of as being in "competition" with an ordinary utility, which must collect 63 cents from its customers for each one dollar of mechanical costs. The existing electric utilities do not fear-in fact they welcome-true competition with competitors who must play by the same rules. If some of the co-ops are ready to leave their legitimate sphere of rural electrification and enter the fray of competition for such customers as industrial plants, they should not only be required to obtain their borrowings in the commercial money markets but their customers should also be required, as the customers of other utilities are required, to contribute their pro rata part to the national budget. This could be accomplished simply by forcing these co-ops which seek to supply industrial and other non-member loads to drop their guise of nonprofit activity, reorganize as ordinary business corporations, and relinquish their tax exemption and Federal subsidy.

Question No. 5

Isn't it true that the construction of power generating facilities by co-ops is necessary to preserve the "bargaining position" of the co-ops in “securing power at reasonable rates and under reasonable terms"?

Translated into understandable English this means that if the co-ops and their customers are going to absolutely avoid their share of contribution to the national budget (contributions like the ordinary consumers of electricity have to make, that is) then the co-ops are going to have to generate their own electricity because if they buy it from tax-paying utilities the co-ops will (as all customers of tax-paying utilities do) have to contribute, partially and indirectly, to this national budget. Isn't it much more "reasonable" if the co-ops and their customers simply leave all such taxes to the electric companies and their customers? What could be more "reasonable"?

Returning to the element of control by Congress-the essential element to be considered in all the REA "bank" proposals because it is that control which the "bank" proposals seek to throw off-it is our plea that Congress tighten such control rather than relinquish it, that Congress force the co-ops and the REA to remain within (and return to if they have strayed from) their original legitimate task of rural electrification and, finally, that Congress enact a set of standards to accomplish such purpose, which standards would be subject to judicial review on petition by any person who is injured by the departure from such standards of either the REA or the individual co-ops.

Within its sphere of legitimate concern the REA has no financing problem which requires the creation of "banks" or other exotic and autonomous vehicles. Such "banks" are needed only if the REA is to be able to realize its aim of a Federally-controlled public power take-over of the electric industry to the extent that it is presently made up of tax-paying (or tax collecting, from the customers, would be more correct) companies.

We do not believe that the REA's aim is the aim of Congress and we do not believe the Congress will, if it understands the true purposes of such "banks," approve them to further such aims.

We appreciate this opportunity to express our views and we respectfully urge that H.R. 14837 and H.R. 14000 and other such measures be defeated.

Respectfully yours,

HOUSTON LIGHTING & POWER CO.,

By P. H. ROBINSON, President.

EXHIBIT A.-Comparison of costs, 7 large investor-owned electric utilities in Texas with all 922 REA cooperatives in the United States, year 1964

[blocks in formation]

Source: Federal Power Commission Statistics of Electric Utilities in the United States 1964, Privately Owned. Rural Electrification Administration, U.S. Department of Commerce 1904 Annual Statistical Report, Rural Electrification Borrowers.

STATEMENT OF ROBERT H. SHORT, VICE PRESIDENT, PORTLAND GENERAL ELECTRIC COMPANY, PORTLAND, OREG.

Portland General Electric Company appreciates the opportunity to submit this statement of our views regarding S. 3720, S. 3337 and H.R. 14837.

Portland General Electric Company is an an investor-owned electric utility serving the lower Willamette Valley of the State of Oregon. It provides electric service to about one million persons in an area covering 4,236 square miles. The City of Portland, the Oregon Capital City of Salem, and 46 other cities and towns are located in the Company's service territory. The Company serves at uniform "postage stamp" rates. The average rate per kilowatt hour is one cent, which is the lowest of any investor-owned utility in the United States. Its rural areas and farms are competely electrified, and the rate schedules to rural areas are identical to those in urban areas.

The State of Oregon has a utility area certification law which tends to restrict electric utility agencies to specified geographical areas. In view of this statute, it is unlikely this legislation will seriously affect Oregon utility agencies. The general nature of the proposed bills, however, is sufficiently significant to justify substantial national discussion of the basic issues involved.

The bills here considered would change the concept of public subsidy for rural electrification to public subsidy for expanded competition between rural electric cooperatives and municipally owned and investor-owned utility systems. The legislative history of the statute which authorized REA makes it clear that the intent and purpose of the law was to encourage rural electrification through the vehicle of federal loans at publicly subsidized rates of interest. The goal of the original law was to electrify areas of the United States which for reasons of economics could not receive central station service from existing municipal or private utilities. This much desired goal has been almost fully achieved. We recognize, however, that even though rural electrification is an accomplished fact, there are many cases where economic assistance continues to be needed. There are areas in Oregon, for example, notably in the southeaster portion of the state, where continued public subsidy of rural electrification is required. The Central Electric Cooperative, the Mid-State Electric Cooperative, the Harney Electric Cooperative, and the Surprise Valley Electric Cooperative serve almost one-fourth of the state's 96,541 square miles. Within this area. however, there resides only one percent of the state's electric customers. Even with the subsidy of 2% money, electric rates in these areas range from 40 to 260 percent higher than those of Portland General Electric. Obviously, these cooperatives need continued public support.

If REA-financed cooperatives become reasonably able to provide service without federal subsidy, some alternative means of financing construction of facilities should be developed. In principle, this alternative means of financing would remove the cooperatives from access to public funds. The legislation under consideration here does not meet the goal.

« PreviousContinue »